A combination of factors
has led to increased participation in international capital markets by frontier
economies in Africa. Not least of these has been the post-crisis global
liquidity environment, characterized by low interest rates in the United States.
As a result, many investors– in search for yield– have been experimenting with
sovereigns beyond the traditional emerging markets.
For developed regions with budget problems, austerity measures may also have slowed the flow of bilateral and multilateral financing that has traditionally been a key funding source for many African sovereigns [1]. Several economies in Africa including Kenya, Tanzania, Zambia, Rwanda, and Ghana among others have taken advantage of the low global interest rates to issue sovereign bonds to finance infrastructure and other spending [2][3][4]. In this policy paper I look at the potential fallout with regards to debt sustainability brought about by this relatively new source of financing.
For developed regions with budget problems, austerity measures may also have slowed the flow of bilateral and multilateral financing that has traditionally been a key funding source for many African sovereigns [1]. Several economies in Africa including Kenya, Tanzania, Zambia, Rwanda, and Ghana among others have taken advantage of the low global interest rates to issue sovereign bonds to finance infrastructure and other spending [2][3][4]. In this policy paper I look at the potential fallout with regards to debt sustainability brought about by this relatively new source of financing.
I study the riskiness of
Eurobond issuance through an analysis of the covariance of external debt
service (including coupon payments of these Eurobonds) with revenue streams of
many of these issuers (commodity exports); the global business cycle; and the global
interest rate (measured by the libor rate). The purpose is to quantify the risk
this new borrowing implies for African sovereigns. I expect strong positive
co-movement in the global business cycle and commodity prices; negative
co-movement between the global interest rate and commodity prices; and the same
for debt service and commodity prices. In the first instance, a growing economy
is characterized by increasing demand for production inputs, which in turn may
raise the price of commodities, ceteris paribus. Frankel (2008) observes that
real interest rates are an important determinant of real commodity prices[5].
According to Frankel
(2008), there are various channels from interest rates to commodity prices but
they all imply a negative relationship between the two variables:
High interest rates
reduce the demand for storable commodities, or increase the supply, through a
variety of channels:
- High
interest rates increase the incentive for extraction today rather than
tomorrow.
- High
interest rates decrease firms’ desire to carry inventories by encouraging
speculators to shift out of spot commodity contracts, and into treasury
bills.
A decrease in real
interest rates has the opposite effect, lowering the cost of carrying
inventories, and raising commodity prices, as happened in the 1970s, and again
during 2001-2004 (ibid). With regard to debt service: increasing borrowing
costs make debt service costly, hence the hypothesis of a positive covariance.
As such the commodity-dependent country that faces a terms of trade
deterioration or low export prices obtains lower fiscal revenues and thus faces
a greater likelihood of default or balance of payments crisis. If my hypothesis
holds, then a borrowing mechanism that addresses such covariances of commodity
prices and ability to pay (a function of export revenues and the world business
cycle) is needed, particularly as non-concessional borrowing gains prominence.
I study debt service in
Zambia (copper exporter), Ghana (oil, cocoa, and gold exporter), Gabon (oil
exporter), Angola (oil) and Nigeria (oil) on the basis of the commodity
intensity of their export and fiscal revenues, which affect ability to service
debts. Moreover these countries have issued Eurobonds or are close to doing so[6] as shown in the image on my cover page. There are
sections in the paper where I also contrast these countries with South Africa a
more developed issuer with diversified exports including manufactures and
minerals, among other things.
While the motivation for
this research is Eurobond issuance, the key variable is debt service throughout
this paper. This is because public and publicly guaranteed debt service is the
sum of principal repayments and interest actually paid in currency, goods, or
services on long-term obligations of public debtors and long-term private
obligations guaranteed by a public entity. Data are usually reported in current
U.S. dollars or as a percentage of GDP. Debt service includes the coupon
payments from the Euro bond. Moreover to study a longer term behavior of the
implied commitments from Eurobond issuance debt service is a common and more
standardized series than spreads.
Methodologically, I
first use time series analyses to study the daily behavior of individual bonds
of Gabon (2007–17 euro bond), Ghana (2007–17 euro bond), Zambia (2013–18 euro
bond), and Nigeria (2012–22 euro bond) in order to understand such factors as
shock persistence and stationarity. This helps us understand the impact on bond
price (hence yield) of shocks to commodity prices and the world business cycle
as these could have far reaching implications on debt sustainability. I then
use the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) database, to estimate
the variance-covariance-matrices of the world business cycle, world interest
rate, and commodity prices. I estimate country fixed effects regressions of
debt service to export ratios against the dollar price of their commodity
exports, the world interest rate, and the world business cycle. I conclude the
methodology section by running the same analyses but with debt service
denominated in commodity volume instead of dollars.
I find that after
linking debt service obligations to commodity prices the sensitivity of debt
service to fluctuations in primary commodity prices and other global
macroeconomic variables is reduced in most countries. This supports the
argument for a form of borrowing that does precisely this. This leads me to the
policy alternatives section in which I argue that commodity bonds provide such
insurance for commodity dependent countries. This is not a new idea so I
discuss this policy option at length with a focus on impediments to its
operationalization. I am grateful to Professor Frankel (my advisor) whose
extensive work on commodity price volatility in low income countries informs
this thesis.
In terms of deliverables
this policy paper will:
- Inform
international financial institutions primarily the IMF, the World Bank,
and the African Development Bank (through the Making Finance Work for
Africa Program –MFW4AP), which give macroeconomic and financial advice to
African countries.
- Provide
a basis for improving the periodic Debt Sustainability Analyses (DSAs)
conducted by the IMF/World Bank.
- Serve as a reference to policy makers looking to issue government debt in international capital markets, and keep debt sustainable in the long run.
[1] Esters, Christian 2013. Standard &
Poor’s. The Growing Allure Of Eurobonds For African Sovereigns.
[2] Barley, Richard 2013. AfricanBonds May Slake Thirst for Yield.
Wallstreet Journal, 4/25/2013
[3] Rudarakanchana Nat, 2013. Forget Emerging Markets: Welcome FrontierMarkets, For Brave
Stock And Bond Investors. International Business Times.
[4] Javier Blas Katrina Manson, 2013.
Financial Times. Sub-Saharan bond rush spreads east to Kenya and Tanzania
[5] Frankel, Jeffrey 2008. AnExplanation for Soaring Commodity Prices. http://www.voxeu.org/article/explanation-soaring-commodity-prices,
Accessed 2/13/2014
[6] Africa Report 2013. Angolapostpones first Eurobond sale again,
Reuters
No comments:
Post a Comment
Constructive feedback is always welcome. Thank you